skip to main | skip to sidebar
GLCtest
  • HOME
    • ABOUT US
    • GLC ANTHOLOGIES
  • LINKS
    • RECOMMENDED SITES
    • DISCLAIMER
  • GLC Global Board
  • AUTHORS
  • CONTACT
  • GLU
  • ICDD
  • Follow Us on Twitter

    26 September 2011

    The dilemma of job creation and decent work

    Edward Webster
    In August 2010 South African government officials began closing down clothing and textile factories in Newcastle, in the province of KwaZulu–Natal. This came in the face of angry protests from the workers because the owners were paying less than the statutory minimum wage of R324 ($49) a week. The factory owners said they could not pay more and survive in the face of cheap Chinese textile imports.
    Globally, the clothing and textile industry is to a large extent controlled by an oligopolistic group of large retailers and branded manufacturers, who stipulate their supply specifications in terms of low price, high quality and short lead times. But due to the strengthening of the local currency (the rand) since 2003, the end of the Multifibre Agreement (MFA) in 2004 and relatively high labour costs, South Africa no longer has a comparative advantage in an integrated global economy.[i]This challenge is not peculiar to South Africa. The existence of fragmented and outsourced manufacturing, accompanied by aggressive buying practices, militates against a living wage in the global apparel sector. This is in spite of the fact that there is general consensus on all sides of the industry that an increase in the unit labour costs by the amount proportional to what is deemed to be a living wage would only marginally impact on the retail price of the garment (Miller and Williams, 2009:104-105).
    The result of these competitive pressures is the undercutting of local jobs from low wage sectors of the global labour force, as the case of Newcastle illustrates, where costs of labour are a small proportion of the total costs in production. On average wages constitute less than one-half of 1% of the retail price of branded sweatshirts. Miller and Williams conclude that progress is possible only through an acceptance of collective bargaining through trade unions in supplier factories.
    Andre Kriel, the general secretary of the Southern African Clothing and Textile Workers Union (SACTWU), takes a similar view:
    “Some Newcastle employers expect us to decrease wages and compete in the world as a low wage country. This is a short term and impractical view. If we drop wages, other countries will respond by dropping theirs further – a vicious downward spiral. Getting trapped in a race to the bottom is not a sustainable option. The other option, which we support, does not focus only on wages but also includes a long–term, sustainable and human rights–based solution. It requires compliance with our laws, decent work, a focus on improving productivity, modernising work, upskilling workers, improving quality, diversifying product range and ensuring reliable delivery times” (Kriel, 2011).
    Workers in the developing world, as early as the seventies and eighties in Brazil, Korea and South Africa, became the architects of their own future. No longer willing to accept their designation as either victims or as labour elite, they took control of their lives, went out on strike and started a struggle for democratic trade unions. While the ILO was debating on how to respond to their ‘discovery” of the informal sector in Kenya in 1972, Ela Bhatt had begun to organise these workers into a union, the Self Employed Women’s Association (SEWA).
    A new labour paradigm has emerged in the Global South that does not see decent work as an obstacle or add-on to development, but is instead attempting to integrate decent work into an alternative developmental path. Work, I suggest, is the missing link in the current discourse on development; none of the dominant theories on globalisation integrate the struggle for decent work into their developmental trajectories. All three dominant theories of globalisation – neo-classical liberalism, the social reformist or anti-capitalist/ autonomist theories that underpin the current anti-globalisation movement and development statism – treat the struggle for decent work as either an obstacle or an add-on (Bowles, 2010).
    In the course of my research on working life I have seen the erosion of standard employment relationships, the growth of insecure and low non-core jobs, together with the expansion of the informal economy and large-scale unemployment. These jobs lack the characteristics of decent work as defined by the ILO; they have, in other words, a decent work deficit.
    This deficit can be expressed as an absence of the four goals of decent work: an absence of sufficient employment opportunities, inadequate social protection, the denial of rights at work, and shortcomings in social dialogue. “It is a measure of the gap between the world that we work in and the hopes that people have for a better life” (ILO, 2001:8). These absences can be expressed in terms of four gaps: an employment gap; a rights gap; a social protection gap; and a social dialogue gap (ibid, 8- 10).
    The economic crisis which began in late 2008 has accelerated this logic leading to the widespread bail-out of banks and now austerity programmes with cutbacks on public sector jobs and benefits. Many countries no longer hire permanent public sector staff and appoint on short term contracts. For those in the informal economy the situation is worse with their incomes being cut by an estimated 50%.
    How can this decent work deficit be reduced? This can only be done, I argue, by developing a long term goal that integrates decent work into a country’s growth path. In other words the goal of decent work should be seen as an objective to be progressively realised. Quite simply this involves accepting that decent work is not an immediately achievable goal. Each country will have to take into account its specific social and economic context and set itself a series of immediate, medium and long term goals.
    Governments, together with their labour movements and employer associations, in some developing countries, have begun to identify how these long term goals can be achieved. The crucial step in advancing this debate was the demonstration that a basic set of social security benefits, or at least parts thereof, are affordable in developing countries. The realisation that, in the short term, it is possible to imagine building a global social floor – a basic pension, child benefits, access to health care, temporary employment guarantee schemes or income transfers for the long term unemployed -broke the spell of the “non-affordability myth” (Cichon, Behrendt and Wodsak, 2011:3).
    But if these policies are to be more than mere rhetoric, resources must be allocated to implement these policy frameworks. The only way to create sustainable employment is through turning “bad” jobs into “good” jobs through skills development and the improvement of infrastructure.
    This attempt at developing an alternative development path is not some way-out revolutionary adventure, “tilting at windmills” as it were. Instead it is swimming very much with the current by grounding political innovation in successful social policy initiatives. This is happening in countries such as Brazil, through a conditional family grant, the Bolsa Familia, in India through the Mahatma Ghandi National Rural Employment Guarantee Scheme (MGNREGS), a guarantee of 100 days paid work for each rural household and South Africa is experimenting with an employment guarantee of two days a week, the Community Work Programme (CWP).
    The Global South faces a massive challenge to overcome the legacy of its past and meet the challenge of globalisation. If we take the modest sum of R1500 per month (250 US dollars) as a minimum for a “decent” wage, then over 10 million people out of South Africa’s workforce of over 19 million suffer from a decent work deficit. But the challenge is not financial; it is one of thinking long term around strategies of future growth. This is a matter of priorities and political will. It was estimated that in India the MGNREGS costs 1.3% of GDP. Estimates for a similar employment scheme in South Africa vary between 1% and 3% of GDP.
    But there are signs of an awakening civil society and a revitalised labour movement in the Global South that could provide the pressure from below that brings together not only wage labour and the great swaths of informal, precarious labour, but also joins them to movements against the commodification of nature and of money in a new employment generating and ecologically sensitive development path.
    [i] It is beyond the scope of this article to examine the validity of employers’ claims that they cannot afford to pay the minimum wage. This would require undertaking a price breakdown of a Newcastle factory and the implications of a minimum labour price/cost floor for clothing retailers in South Africa.

    Download this article as pdf

    Professor Webster is currently leading a research team designed to develop a diagnostic tool to track the goal of decent work in the province of Gauteng , South Africa. His most recently co-authored book, Grounding Globalisation: Labour in the Age of Insecurity, won the American Sociological Association (ASA) prize for the best book on labour in 2008.

    References
    Bowles, P (2010) Labour and globalisation, Global labour journal, Volume I, Number 1.
    Cichon, M, Behrendt, C and V. Wodsak. 2011. The UN Social Protection Floor Initiative: turning the Tide at the ILO Conference 2011. Friedrich Ebert Stiftung
    Miller, D and Williams, P. 2009. “What price a Living Wage? Implementation Issues in the Quest for Decent Wages I the Global Apparel Sector’, Global Social Policy: Volume 9(1):99-125.

    19 September 2011

    Argentina’s ‘Year of Decent Work’, a critical assessment

    Bruno Dobrusin
    The centre-left government of Cristina Kirchner declared 2011 as the ‘Year of Decent Work’ in Argentina, following consultations with the ILO and other international institutions regarding government programmes during the current global economic crisis. The Kirchner administration has indeed promoted several counter-cyclical measures to fight against the global recession and maintain levels of employment in the country. The relative success of these policies, together with the continuous economic growth that Argentina has witnessed since 2003, led the government to tour the international forums such as the G20 meetings and claim that Argentina is an example of a successful response to the crisis. Despite the improvements in the overall economy and the high levels of employment that the country is witnessing, the so-called ‘model’ is far from ideal, and has to be questioned on its main claims. This article discusses the recent improvements as presented by the government and the counter-facts suggested by a recent study carried on by the Workers’ Confederation of Argentina (CTA)[i].
    The Decent Work Agenda proposed by the ILO is based on four pillars: employment creation, rights at work, extending social protection and promoting social dialogue. The main focus here is on employment creation in Argentina over the past few years, and on the quality of employment created. Since 2003 Argentina has had a remarkable economic recovery, with an average eight percent annual growth. The devaluation of the currency in late 2002 led to the protection of an important part of industrial production, which explains the generation of employment in the time period. Between 2002 and 2007, the rate of employment increased to levels unseen since 1974, creating approximately 3.7 million new jobs out of which half are in the formal sector[ii], with the industrial sector as the main participant. It has to be recognised that the success of the industry is the reduction of the labour cost in dollars of an important industrial sector, which, due to the low technological component, can compete with imported products through the lowering of salaries in dollars. The leading sectors in the period, the automobile and the iron and steel industries, do not need the exchange rate protection nor did they contribute to employment recovery. Towards 2009, with higher production, employment in the automobile companies was lower than that registered in the middle of the 1990s. The reason is that it is an enclave industry, with small participation of production from Argentina
    In the period 2003-2010 social protection was improved, with a current 86 percent of the population receiving benefits from social security systems (both private and public), up from 60 percent in 2003[iii]. In addition to this, the government has also produced a recovery in the minimum wage negotiations by bringing back the Minimum Wage Council, with participation by unions, the state and the employers. This has produced a consistent increase in the minimum wage, at an average rate of 20 percent a year. This set of achievements is being presented by the Kirchner administration to the G20 as an example for other countries to follow. The ILO has supported the government in its promotion of a firm decent work agenda. However, behind this policy, there is a harsh reality that is not being heard about Argentina and the labour policies of the current administration.
    There are a number of reasons that justify the assessment that Argentina is not indeed the paradise of decent work. According to two different studies made by alternative trade unions, the employment situation in the country is actually grimmer than that presented by the government. The main difference in the evaluation of these studies is the statistics used. The government has consistently denied the inflation levels and has intervened in the National Institute of Statistics, through appointing a new director and changing the figures of inflation on a monthly basis. This arbitrary decision has been consistently criticised by the workers’ representatives in the Institute. When we take the statistics produced by other public non-intervened institutes, employment figures remain virtually the same since 2007, without improvements in the 8 percent unemployment figure[iv]. If we look at employment creation, it was significant in the period between 2003-2006 that an average of 750,000 jobs was created per year, but it declined in the period between 2007 and 2010 to an average of only 200,000 jobs annually[v]. Moreover, the government claims that informality has decreased over the past decade, when it actually remains at historically high levels. Out of the 3,7 million jobs created, more than half are in the informal sector, which remains at an overall level of 40 percent of the employed population[vi]. Among the youth, informality is even higher, reaching 60 percent of the employed[vii], and with worse working conditions. These factors are closely related to the still relevant 30 percent poverty levels, and just over 5 million people below the level of extreme poverty[viii]. Argentina is not then a good example of a country overcoming the decent work deficit and there remains a need for significant change in the working conditions of the majority of Argentinian citizens.
    In reality, informal and precarious working conditions continue in Argentina. Only the salary of the formal workers compensates for the increases in prices, leaving a minority that can sustain their living standards. The current real wage is similar to that of low earners in 2001 at the moment of the economic crisis. The unemployment rate continues to be greater than the same rate in the early 1990s, and it is still much higher than in the 1970s and 1980s. In addition, the stages of ‘social dialogue’ promoted by the government only include the main trade union confederation (CGT), a key ally of the government. There is no intention in the Kirchner administration to recognise any of the alternative trade union confederations, countering the demands made consistently by the ILO in its Freedom of Association reports.
    At the September G20 meeting of Labour Ministers, the Argentine government will present their response as the example for other G20 governments to follow, especially those undergoing economic crisis. However, Argentina is still far from an ideal place for labour policies and labour rights. As presented here, the country still has to discuss the productive and developmental model that currently produces immense wealth and a GDP growth of 8 percent a year, but it provides these high profits for a small group of heavily concentrated business groups, mostly foreign, and keeps workers in precarious working conditions.
    [i] IDEF-CTA. “Sobre el trabajo decente. Contexto general, informalidad laboral y políticas publicas”, July 2011.
    [ii] Labour Ministry of Argentina. “Trabajo, Empleo y Ocupacion. Una Mirada a sectores económicos desde las relaciones laborales y la innovación”, June 2010, p. 43
    [iii] Labour Ministry of Argentina. “Trabajo y Empleo en el Bicentenario. Cambio en la dinámica del empleo y la protección social para la inclusión social. Periodo 2003-2010”, September 2010., p.49.
    [iv] IDEF-CTA, p.2.
    [v] IDEF-CTA, p.4
    [vi] Ibid, p.21.
    [vii] Ibid, p.27.
    [viii] Ibid,p.14

    Download this article as pdf

    Bruno Dobrusin is MA candidate at the Tata Institute of Social Sciences, Global Labour University. He is also advisor to the International Relations Secretariat of the Argentine Workers' Confederation (CTA) and research scholar at the Institute of Studies of State and Participation, belonging to the State Employees' Union of Argentina. He is currently involved in the follow-up of the process of regional integration within South America for CTA.

    12 September 2011

    The euro crisis and the European trade union movement

    Vasco Pedrina
    After successfully bailing out banks and adopting a first wave of economic recovery measures, the authorities of the European Union (EU) and its member states began to impose draconian, anti-social austerity plans from the beginning of spring 2010. These plans stem from an increasingly coordinated policy at the EU level, which is entering a new phase with the “Euro-Plus Pact” and the “enlarged bailout plan”. Dressed up as part of a fight against “macroeconomic imbalances”, new mechanisms are to be put in place. These will provide EU authorities with the means to step up the pressure for general social dismantling. Concretely, this amounts to a “wages straitjacket” that calls into question the autonomy of social partners (one of the pillars of the “European social model”), raises the retirement age across European countries and introduces legislation to curb national debt. This policy is not only having dramatic social repercussions. It is also heading up an economic blind alley that is putting the euro at risk.
    At its Congress in Athens in May 2011, the European Trade Union Confederation (ETUC) reaffirmed its opposition to the currently prevailing neoliberal economic policies and once again demanded a change of course. The only conceivable way of pulling the eurozone out of crisis is a combination of measures aimed both at boosting economic growth and at a gradual reduction of debt levels and macroeconomic imbalances. The ETUC is calling for a “New Social and Green Deal” consisting of a large investment plan, the issuing of eurobonds, low-interest liquidity provision by the European Central Bank (ECB) and a low-carbon industrial policy underpinned by fiscal reforms, which should include a tax on financial transactions. As far as Greece is concerned, it is now clear that it will not be able to break out of the present vicious circle without a really substantial recovery plan financed by the EU within the framework of a sort of Marshall Plan for countries in distress. The ETUC is also demanding a thorough overhaul of the “Euro Pact” – particularly the part on wage and retirement measures.
    Mobilising against social suffocation
    To back this alternative economic programme, the ETUC has held four European action days in the past two years. Demonstrations and strikes spread across many European countries, but they did not build enough pressure to halt the neoliberal steamroller. Back in the days of the “social democratic compromise” under the presidency of Jacques Delors, protests of that size would have been seen as a good reason for getting down to negotiations. Today, that is no longer so. Neither the EU authorities nor those of the member states were swayed by the protest action. True, the European trade union movement has, in the meantime, managed to get the most reactionary legal provisions expunged from the Euro Pact, but its antisocial thrust remains, as do the national austerity plans. At the same time, some pillars of the “European social model” are under relentless attack. Symptomatic of this is the EU political authorities’ refusal to correct the precedent created by the European Court of Justice (ECJ) in the Laval, Viking, Rüffert and Luxembourg cases of 2007/08. Through these rulings, the ECJ called into question the basic principles of social Europe, such as the precedence of basic social rights over the economic freedoms of the internal market, the principle of “equal pay for equal work in the same place”, the right to strike in order to combat wage dumping, and the autonomy of the social partners.
    European trade unionism at a crossroads
    “Social Europe” is under pressure. Clearly, there will be no change of course unless pressure from strikes and political action coordinated at the European level builds up on a scale quite different to anything that has been achieved up to now. And yet, in the wake of the crisis, unions are falling back to defensive struggle positions within national frameworks. Evidently, the unions have put too little energy into European mobilising. Even 80,000 people on the march in Brussels no longer have such a great impact.
    The time has come to re-examine our strategy if we do not want to look on helplessly as the European trade union movement slides into irremediable decline. The current debate on this issue within the political left and the trade union movement is seeing the emergence of two currents of thought. One of them advocates a strategy of “renationalising policy”. Those supporting this “fallback strategy” argue that, as the EU is on the road to neoliberal damnation, the only realistic response would be to set up resistance networks to defend the social State within the national framework. The left-wing supporters of this position are, de facto, putting themselves in the same camp as the conservatives within the trade union movement who, like quite a lot of Nordic confederations, believe that the “lone road” is the best way of defending their “Nordic social model”, even though that model is more and more threatened by new developments within the EU.
    The other school of thought advocates an “offensive strategy” of Europeanising social struggles. Their argument is that the only positive alternative is a quantitative and qualitative leap forward in joint political action and mobilising across Europe. But the days in which such a leap might still be made successfully are numbered. There is a serious risk that the Euro Pact, together with the whole series of austerity plans, will cause such an increase in the imbalances between and within countries that the social and political tensions will become unbearable, due to the rise of populist forces. The already growing tensions among trade union confederations in Europe and among confederations within individual countries (such as Italy) give some idea of where such developments could lead, namely to a catastrophic paralysis of the labour movement.
    Levers for Europeanising social struggles
    The strikes and mobilisations over the past two years in various European countries have led to the emergence of new demands, new forms of action and new alliances from which useful lessons can be drawn for the Europeanisation of trade union resistance networks. At the same time, other routes may lead to the qualitative leap described above. At the ETUC congress, two proposals were discussed for campaigns with the potential to launch a real, coordinated counter-offensive.
    One of these proposals concerns the response to the currently prevailing neoliberal economic policies. It is based on the alternative ETUC economic programme mentioned above, on reinforced coordination of bargaining policy and on an offensive for a European minimum wage policy and against the precarisation of jobs. Workplace strike capacities in support of European demands need to be strengthened in order to achieve these objectives. Granted, the ETUC congress did adopt a proposal from the Spanish confederations CCOO and UGT, calling for serious examination of the feasibility of coordinated strikes or a European general strike, but it did so without conviction. Clearly, the political will is still lacking, but this state of mind could change if the pressure of suffering continues to mount, which it probably will.
    The second proposal, entitled “Equal Pay, Equal Rights”, aims to give new impetus to the struggle for workers’ rights, which are under attack almost everywhere, as well as the struggle against wage dumping. To support this campaign, the Swiss Federation of Trade Unions has proposed the launching of a European Citizens’ Initiative (ECI) entitled “For a Europe without wage dumping – Priority for basic social rights over economic freedoms”. Under the new Lisbon treaty, citizens can petition EU authorities on new policies and legislations with one million signatures. An ECI of this kind would be aimed at giving the EU a mandate for the legislative measures needed to ensure that precedence for basic social rights over economic freedoms becomes generally applicable throughout the European Union.
    Launching such an ECI would enable broad awareness-raising (and mobilisation) in workplaces and among the union rank-and-file right across Europe – something that has not been possible so far. Other social movements and political forces that share our concerns about the future of social Europe could be associated with the ECI. The ETUC congress accepted this second proposal, which a working group is to put into concrete form by the end of this year. But it did not give a clear green light to the decisive lever for such a campaign, namely the ECI. The reservations come from countries such as France, the UK and Italy, whose union confederations say they have no tradition of collecting signatures for this kind of instrument. They are underestimating the potential of a citizens’ initiative as an instrument of decentralised awareness-raising and political pressure for a common objective throughout Europe.
    The ETUC congress could have sent out a strong signal for a large-scale political and trade union European counter-offensive. The lack of energy to go down that road is probably due to the way that unions in quite a few countries have been hit and weakened. Nonetheless, it may well be that a response on a scale to match the current challenges will become possible once the pressure of suffering rises even further, and people will be forced to realise that a social and political turning-point cannot be reached without strengthened trade union policy coordination beyond national borders. This will require an alliance with all interested social movements and political forces. The future of social Europe and of the European integration process is at stake.

    Download this article as pdf

    Vasco Pedrina is the National Secretary of the Swiss inter-professional trade union Unia and Vice-President of the Building and Wood Workers’ International (BWI). He represents the Swiss Federation of Trade Unions (SGB/USS) on the ETUC Executive Committee.

    5 September 2011

    7 Reasons why a Universal Income makes Sense in Middle-Income Countries




    Hein Marais
    Is job creation really the best way to seek wellbeing for all in countries with chronic, high unemployment? No – especially not in a wealthy middle-income country like South Africa, where very high unemployment combines with high poverty rates. Here are 7 reasons why a universal income grant makes more sense.
    1. EARNING A DECENT SECURE WAGE IS NOT A PROSPECT FOR MILLIONS OF SOUTH AFRICANS
    While the rewards of South Africa’s modest economic growth are cornered in small sections of society, close to half the population lives in poverty, and income inequality is wider than ever before.
    Job creation improved modestly as economic growth accelerated in the early 2000s. About 3 million ‘employment opportunities’ were created in 2002-08. The semantics are important. Very many of those ‘opportunities’ did not merit being called ‘jobs’. They divided roughly equally between the formal and informal sectors, and occurred mainly via public works programmes, business services, and the wholesale and retail trade sectors. A lot of them were crummy, insecure and poorly paid.
    The average unemployment rate for middle-income countries is in the 5-10% range; in South Africa, it is about 25%. Add workers who have given up looking for jobs, and the actual rate sits around the 35% mark. Since late 2008, the private sector has been shedding jobs, and the public sector’s been trying to add new ones. It’s an endless game of catch-up.
    2. HAVING A JOB DOES NOT AUTOMATICALLY SHIELD AGAINST POVERTY
    Having waged work is the single-most important factor deciding whether or not a household will be poor. But earning a wage does not guarantee that you won’t be poor.
    Vast numbers of workers earn wages so low and on such poor terms that their jobs don’t shield them against poverty. Increasingly that applies also to formal sector jobs. Almost one fifth (some 1.4 million) of formal sector workers earned less than R 1 000 (USD 125) a month in the mid-2000s, according to Statistics SA data.
    Two factors drive these trends: the shift towards the use of casual and outsourced labour, and the related decline in real wages for low-skilled workers.
    The average real wage is being propped up by the improved fortunes of comparatively small numbers of high-skilled, high-wage workers. Workers without tertiary qualifications lost about 20% of their average real wage. And women in the formal sector earned less in real and relative terms in 2005, compared with 1995.
    From the late-1970s into the 1990s, South African companies tried to compete and maintain profit levels by upgrading machinery and introducing new technologies to achieve higher productivity and reduce reliance on militant, organised workers.
    Eventually the dividends dwindled, and currency crashes since the mid-1990s inflated the cost of imported technology.
    The hunt for profit required another squeeze, and it was applied to the wages and terms of employment of workers who are not shielded sufficiently by labour laws and shopfloor organising.
    Company profits as a share of national income rose from 26% in 1993 to 31% in 2004, while workers’ wages fell from 57% to 52%.
    Companies now rely on a shrinking core of skilled, full-time workers and a larger stock of less-skilled and badly paid casual or out-sourced labour. By 2008, according to the Labour Ministry, about half the workforce was in casual and temporary jobs.
    Job creation is vital. But it’s not a match-winner anymore – not in the kind of economy and labour market that defines South Africa. The quest for more – and better jobs – has to occur as part of the wider realization of social rights.
    3. SOCIAL GRANTS SEPARATE MILLIONS FROM DESTITUTION BUT IT IS ILL-SUITED TO TODAY’S REALITIES
    The impact of the social grant system is beyond dispute. According to Statistics SA, the increase in incomes among the poorest 30% of South Africans after 2001 was mainly due to social grants (especially the child support grant). They’re the best poverty-alleviating tool South Africa has at the moment.
    Beneficiaries rose radically since 2000. The 2.6 million recipients of pensions and social grants increased to about 14 million in 2010. About 43% of households in 2007 received at least one social grant; in half of them, pensions or grants were the main sources of income.
    A large proportion of low-income households would probably be unviable without these grants.
    The current social protection system hinges on the fiction that every worker, sooner or later, will find a decent job. Thus the grants were designed to assist people who, due to age or disability, cannot reasonably be expected to fend for themselves by selling their labour. Meanwhile, the employed have access to employer- and worker-subsidised protection (all tied to employment status).
    But large numbers of vulnerable workers are not eligible for these state grants, and do not benefit from employment-based provisions.
    4. TARGETED AND MEANS-TESTED SOCIAL PROTECTION IS BURDENSOME, COSTLY AND HUMILIATING ADMINISTRATION
    Most states prefer to ration cash grants by targeting them and tying them to certain conditions. South Africa is no different (though only the child support grant is nominally conditional at this point).
    This is administratively expensive, and it tends to be difficult, especially when it is tough to determine an individual’s income, and when that income is likely to fluctuate significantly.
    It runs the risk of creating arbitrary divides between those who benefit from social grants and those who do not. Which is why critics regard the approach as expensive, inefficient and ‘offensive to basic egalitarian principles’, as Guy Standing puts it.
    Most means-tested social grants involve burdensome and humiliating interactions with the state that basically involve ‘proving’ to a stranger that you’re poor and unable to fend for yourself and your family. This is why huge stigma and shame tend to attach to them.
    A universal income grant would be available to all adult citizens, and would be neither conditional, nor targeted or means-tested. The tax system would be used to retrieve (and help finance) the grants from individuals who don’t need them because their incomes are high enough. The grants would form a cornerstone of a broader social protection system.
    5. A UNIVERSAL INCOME IS DEVELOPMENTAL AND WOULD BOOST WELLBEING
    Cash transfers bring powerful anti-poverty, developmental and economic benefits. The observed effects include reduced stunting in children and better nutrition levels, and higher school enrolment of young children.
    In a localized, universal income pilot project in Namibia, child malnutrition declined and school attendance increased significantly within 6 months. Recipients also became more active in income-generating activities.
    Financial simulations have shown that a universal grant as small as R 100 per month could close South Africa’s poverty gap by 74%,[1] and lift about six million people above a poverty line of R 400 (USD 50) per month.
    Cash grants can also help drive more inclusive patterns of growth. Brazil’s expansion of social transfers (especially via the bolsa familia, a conditional grant) along with the extension of the minimum wage has boosted internal demand for local products and services, and aided the growth of formal jobs, as Janine Berg shows in a recent paper.[2]
    6. A UNIVERSAL INCOME CAN BE A POWERFUL EMANCIPATORY TOOL, ESPECIALLY FOR WORKERS
    Cash grants contain a radical, emancipating potential. The key is to uncouple them from the labour market, which a universal income grant can achieve.
    This is a potentially radical and subversive turn that confronts the ‘double separation’ that is typically imposed on workers – separation from the means of production and from the means of subsistence.
    The impact potentially reaches much farther than gains in social justice.
    A universal income has the potential to improve the wages and terms of employment for low-skilled workers. If the bare necessities of life can be secured elsewhere, demeaning and hyper-exploitative wage labour is no longer the ‘only option’.
    Its most subversive effect is to equip people with the freedom not to sell their labour and to withdraw, at least sporadically, from the ‘race to the bottom’ between low-skilled workers in high unemployment settings.
    Thus a universal income can endow the weakest with bargaining power. Linked with other efforts to strengthen wellbeing and expand the content of citizenship, it can contribute toward significant redistribution of power, time and liberty. It also challenges one of the anchoring principles of Anglo-capitalism, which binds employment and citizenship together.
    7. A UNIVERSAL INCOME TREATS WOMEN AS CITIZENS, NOT MERELY AS CAREGIVERS AND BEARERS OF CHILDREN
    Millions of women in SA have entered the labour market since 1980s, despite their exceptionally poor job and wage prospects. Three quarters (75%) of African women younger than 30 years are unemployed. Most who do find employment tend to work part-time, for low wages and in highly exploitative conditions.
    Yet women also bear the bulk of responsibility for social reproduction, and they head more than 40% of households, the majority of them single-parent, impoverished households.
    Overall, the sexual division of labour in both the domestic sphere and labour market remains structured in ways that enable men to monopolise full-time and better-paying jobs, while women perform most of the household labour. Men, whether employed or not, continue to ‘free ride’ on women’s work – paid or not.
    A guaranteed universal income challenges these arrangements, by helping provide currently inaccessible economic independence, and by strengthening the negotiating position of women who do enter the labour market.
    CONCLUSION
    More jobs are vital and feasible. However, the quest for more jobs has to occur as part of a wider realization of social rights. A universal income grant would be a powerful intervention for radically reducing the depth and scale of impoverishment, and for enhancing liberty.
    [1] The poverty gap refers to the total income shortfall of households living below the poverty line. A narrower poverty gap means more households would edge closer to, or above the poverty line.
    [2] Changes in labour market and social policies boosted consumption and economic growth in rural and poor areas, and created a steady demand for small retailers and service providers. That boost in demand also affected other parts of the value chain, including formal manufacturing and distribution (Berg, 2010). See Berg, J. (2010). “Laws or luck? Understanding rising formality in Brazil in the 2000s”. Working Paper no. 5. ILO Office in Brazil. ILO.

    Download this article as pdf

    Writer and journalist HEIN MARAIS is the author of the new book ‘South Africa Pushed to the Limit: The political economy change’, published by UCT Press and Zed Books. It is available online and at good bookstores.

    Newer Posts Older Posts Home

    Share

    Twitter Facebook Stumbleupon Favorites More

    Subscribe to the Mailing List

    If you want to subscribe to the GLC mailing list, please click here or send an email to "sympa@ilo.org" with subject "sub list-glcolumn".

    Contribute to the GLC

    If you want to contribute to the Global Labour Column, please read here the Guidelines for Contributions

    Languages






    Donations

    More Info

    Popular Posts

      From Financial Crisis to Stagnation: The Destruction of Shared Prosperity and the Role of Economics
      Trade Unions, Class Struggle and Development
      Supporting Dissent versus Being Dissent

    TAGS

    Financial Crisis Trade Unions Neoliberalism Globalisation Labour Market Development Strategies Wage Decent Work Growth Social Movements Workers' rights Collective Bargaining Financial Market Labour Standards Financial Regulation Inequality Social Security Tax Europe Fiscal Space Public Investment Social Democracy Corporate Governance Economic Democracy Struggle Competitiveness Environment Global Warming Informal Economy Care Work Central Bank Domestic Workers Progressive alliances Business and Human Rights Capital Flight Economic Development Online Campaigning Pensions Public Works Programmes

    PUBLICATIONS

    Click here to view more

    Blog Archive

    • ►  2012 (12)
      • ►  May (1)
      • ►  April (2)
      • ►  March (3)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (2)
    • ▼  2011 (39)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (4)
      • ►  October (3)
      • ▼  September (4)
        • The dilemma of job creation and decent work
        • Argentina’s ‘Year of Decent Work’, a critical asse...
        • The euro crisis and the European trade union movement
        • 7 Reasons why a Universal Income makes Sense in Mi...
      • ►  August (3)
      • ►  July (2)
      • ►  June (3)
      • ►  May (3)
      • ►  April (4)
      • ►  March (4)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (2)
    • ►  2010 (39)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (5)
      • ►  October (4)
      • ►  September (2)
      • ►  August (2)
      • ►  July (3)
      • ►  June (4)
      • ►  May (1)
      • ►  April (4)
      • ►  March (4)
      • ►  February (4)
      • ►  January (3)
    • ►  2009 (5)
      • ►  December (3)
      • ►  November (2)

    Popular Posts

      From Financial Crisis to Stagnation: The Destruction of Shared Prosperity and the Role of Economics
      Trade Unions, Class Struggle and Development
      Supporting Dissent versus Being Dissent

     
    Copyright © 2011 GLCtest | Powered by Blogger
    Design by Free WordPress Themes | Bloggerized by Lasantha - Premium Blogger Themes | 100 WP Themes